The Voluntary Market Approach
On the back of the rapid growth in the voluntary carbon market, there is an expectation that a similar credit-based approach can be rolled out for biodiversity and work is already underway to make that happen. Land managers who enrich the ecology of their estates could have that biodiversity gain verified, selling credits to businesses that want to (claim to) be ‘nature positive’.
It sounds straightforward, but several aspects of biodiversity gain make its tokenisation more difficult than is the case for carbon emissions. For starters, desirable biodiversity outcomes are subjective in a way that emissions reductions aren’t; not every land manager, or business, agrees on what wildlife should exist in which landscapes. In Scotland, for instance, moorland is a contested habitat, which some see as denuded and low in species diversity and others view as a nature-rich repository of important breeding bird populations. Such views are intimately tied up with cultural values, individual livelihoods and landscape aesthetics, which makes a universal, objective measure of biodiversity gain difficult to produce.
For the buyers of biodiversity credits, too, the need to be ‘nature positive’ is often not felt as keenly as a requirement to be ‘net zero’. Every business is directly responsible for greenhouse gas emissions but for lots of companies their impacts on nature are less apparent, which can reduce the sense of responsibility they feel to pay for mitigation. This is why the work of the TFND is so important, as it will highlight the nature-related impacts, dependencies and risks businesses face, making clear the need to be (and often the business case for being) nature positive.
Finally, the metrics required to substantiate a biodiversity gain are numerous and it isn’t always apparent which ones to use. Should a land manager measure changes in the abundance of insect populations for instance, or would vegetation surveys be more useful? What if their interventions are only targeting one rare or charismatic species in particular? What if some species benefit from the change in habitat quality, but others fare worse? These sorts of trade-offs will almost inevitably occur and, again, they introduce a value-laden element to measuring biodiversity, which makes its standardisation more complex and contested.
The compliance market approach
Despite these challenges of standardisation, the UK government has created a compliance market for biodiversity in England under the legislation contained in the Environment Act (2021).
The Act requires that developers deliver a net gain for biodiversity, by ensuring a minimum 10% uplift in local biodiversity as a result of their developments. DEFRA has created a metric that allows biodiversity losses and enhancements to be quantified, with developers obliged to purchase offsets if they cannot deliver the biodiversity gain on site.
The result is that most developers will now have to pay for biodiversity units, generated offsite by third parties, to fulfil their statutory obligations. The resulting flows of money will see huge investment being channelled into habitat creation and enhancement right across the country, as land managers capitalise on the opportunity to deliver biodiversity uplift on less agriculturally-productive land.
None of this is to say that England’s biodiversity net gain (BNG) market is perfect. The DEFRA metric has been criticised for its coarse resolution – it uses habitat not species-level data – and there is widespread disapproval of the exemption for national infrastructure projects. There are also concerns that funding for nature being yoked to continued housebuilding is fundamentally unsustainable. However, the overall approach of the UK government has to be seen as progressive. They have created a market for biodiversity where demand is assured, where the metrics have been standardised and where the financial incentive for land managers is significant. Now it’s for Scotland, Northern Ireland and Wales to follow suit and roll out their own versions of BNG.
The outcomes-based approach
Payments for outcomes are growing in popularity, with a variety of ecosystem services now being financed through environmental or ‘green’ bonds. This approach is effective at driving private finance into projects, with investors providing the initial capital that a project needs. However, its true utility is determined by the ultimate buyer of the outcome, and whether they are a public or private entity.
If biodiversity gain is the outcome being paid for, it is hard to imagine the payor being anything other than a public-sector or charitable organisation. For green bonds to truly drive private finance into the restoration of nature, the end buyer must also be a private company. Otherwise, the state is footing the bill and could perhaps fund the project more efficiently through grants or a subsidy.
Once again, the need for strong and assured private sector demand for biodiversity gain comes to the fore. It is the essential prerequisite for driving large amounts of private finance into this space.